Peter Neary, a member of IGM’s panel of European economic experts, passed away in June 2021 – a sad loss for the whole economic research community. On VoxEU, Patrick Honohan of Trinity College Dublin, a fellow Irishman and member of the European panel, co-authored an appreciation of Peter, whom he and Cormac o’Grada describe as ‘one of the profession’s European leaders, both in terms of the depth and range of his research and his role as a wizard of organizational development’.

There have also been obituaries on his Oxford college website, and in the Irish Times and the Irish Independent. In May, former colleagues of Peter’s at University College Dublin organized an online conference to discuss his far-ranging work, which included research on imperfect competition in international markets, trade policy, multiproduct firms, and the specific concerns of resource-rich economies. On the day he died, as one of his sons tweeted, he was awarded an honorary doctorate from the National University of Ireland.

To mark Peter’s passing, we invited both our European and US panels to express their views on aspects of his work. We asked the experts whether they agreed or disagreed with the following statements, and, if so, how strongly and with what degree of confidence:

(a) The introduction of even small trade frictions between neighboring countries can result in significant economic damage, particularly to smaller exporting firms.

(b) A national economic boom based on natural resources is likely to harm other sectors of the economy, particularly manufacturing firms.

Of our 43 US experts, 37 participated in this survey; of our 48 European experts, 37 participated – for a total of 74 expert reactions.

Trade frictions and exporting firms

On the first statement about the economic damage that the introduction of small trade frictions can cause to smaller exporting firms, a majority of respondents on both panels agree, although agreement is stronger among the European panel. Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 30% of the European panel strongly agree, 49% agree, 21% are uncertain, and 0% disagree. Among the US panel (again weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response), 61% agree, 36% are uncertain, and 3% disagree.

Overall, across both panels, 29% strongly agree, 54% agree, 15% are uncertain, and 3% disagree (the totals don’t always sum to 100 because of rounding).

Among the short comments that the experts are able to include in their responses, several consider the wording of the statement insufficiently specific. For example, Pinelopi Goldberg at Yale, who expresses ‘no opinion’, says: ‘Not clear what “small” trade frictions are and what “significant” economic damage means.’

Three panelists who opt for ‘uncertain’ in their response contribute similar views: David Autor at MIT comments: ‘This is predicted by theory. But frictionless trade between industrial countries is non-existent. So, what does adding a “small” friction mean?’ His MIT colleague Daron Acemoglu states ‘”Significant” here is very unclear. It can have a proportionately large effect on small firms, but unclear in the aggregate.’ And Caroline Hoxby at Stanford adds: ‘I tend to agree with the spirit of this query, but “small” trade frictions seem too poorly defined for me to give an answer. 1%, 5%, 10%?’

Ricardo Reis at the London School of Economics also refers to the wording although he agrees with the statement – ‘”Significant” is in the eye of the beholder, but literature has quantified multiple relevant channels’ – directing us to studies of the US gains from trade and the consequences of globalization. Pete Klenow at Stanford also provides a reference: to a study of the impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and industry productivity.

Among other panelists who agree or strongly agree with the statement, some provide reasons why it might be true. Larry Samuelson at Yale states: ‘ The presence of a home bias, in various forms, suggests that even small frictions can be important.’ Christopher Udry at Northwestern adds: ‘Because, for example, network effects can generate feedback that reinforces the small frictions.’ And Jan Pieter Krahnen at Goethe University Frankfurt comments: ‘An example can always be constructed that confirms the statement – the question is whether it generalizes to very generic settings.’

Although expressing agreement, Franklin Allen at Imperial cautions: ‘There are complex potential trade-offs here. Frictions can prevent exports but they also prevent imports with an ambiguous net effect.’ And Patrick Honohan notes that an absence of trade frictions is rare: ‘Some cross-border frictions are usual. The almost frictionless situation in the EU is the exception – Brexit displays the result.’

Oliver Hart at Yale, who says he is uncertain, adds: ‘Under classical conditions small frictions have second order effects. So it depends on how important price rigidities, etc., are.’ And Robert Hall at Stanford disagrees with the statement in more ways than one, commenting: ‘Small frictions have small effects. And we should not be concerned with harm to firms or industries, only to people.’

Dutch disease

On the second statement about the harm that a natural resources boom can cause to other sectors of the economy (sometimes called ‘the natural resource curse’ or ‘Dutch disease’), just over two-thirds of respondents across both panels agree. Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 12% of the European panel strongly agree, 58% agree, 25% are uncertain, 2% disagree, and 4% strongly disagree. Among the US panel (again weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response), 5% strongly agree, 54% agree, 37% are uncertain, and 4% disagree.

Overall, across both panels, 6% strongly agree, 62% agree, 29% are uncertain, and 2% disagree.

Among the comments, Pol Antras at Harvard, who agrees, makes explicit the link to Peter’s most cited paper, written with Max Corden: ‘This is one of Peter Neary’s great contributions to Economics, particularly exploring various channels through which it can happen. RIP.’ So too does Oliver Hart, although he opts for ‘uncertain’: ‘My reading of the classic Corden-Neary paper is that the effects can be ambiguous.’

Among those who agree or strongly agree, some explain potential mechanisms. Patrick Honohan explains: ‘Due not only to sectoral competition for labor, but also to the way natural resources tend to attract venal politicians.’ Robert Shimer at Chicago notes: A natural resource boom drives up wages and other non-tradable prices, but this doesn’t mean it is inefficient!’ And Pete Klenow suggests: ‘Such booms crowd out employment in other sectors’, adding a link to evidence from giant oil discoveries.

Ricardo Reis, who says he is uncertain – ‘ It seems to depend on the country’s circumstances, and especially on the policies adopted in response’ – also provides some references: to a survey of the natural resource curse; a study of Dutch disease in Indonesia; and another of modern America.

Many panelists comment on how the outcome from a natural resource boom depends on the policy response. Among those who agree with the statement, Jean-Pierre Danthine at Paris School of Economics concludes: ‘Although appropriate policies can be used to counter the impact.’ And Larry Samuelson says: ‘Much depends on how the resource boom is handled; we have examples of cases that have worked well and examples of disasters.’

Two others who agree with the statement mention the case of Norway, widely seen as a case that has worked well. Charles Wyplosz at the Graduate Institute, Geneva, notes: ‘Aka Dutch Disease. Unless government owns resource and invest proceeding abroad, the Norwegian way.’ And Marco Pagano at Università di Napoli Federico II says: ‘It very much depends on the economic policy response: see Norway as a counter-example to the well-known “curse of raw materials”.’

Several panelists who say they are uncertain have similar views. Franklin Allen states: ‘The outcome depends on a number of characteristics such as the size of the economy. Result may hold for small ones but maybe not large ones.’ And Jan Pieter Krahnen says: ‘It all depends whether or not the other sectors can adjust smoothly to the rise in factor prices driven by the boom in some sectors.’

Similarly, Kenneth Judd at Stanford comments: ‘Discovery of natural resources will reallocate factors of production, but no more so than other changes.’ And Daron Acemoglu notes: ‘The answer would be yes for manufacturing that does not use the resource in question as input. Otherwise, it could be positive.’

Three panelists who express uncertainty return to the role of politics and policy: Sergei Guriev at Sciences Po says: ‘The impact on other sectors depends on the quality of economic and political institutions and on policy response to the boom.’ Hilary Hoynes at Berkeley notes: ‘Whether this were true or not would depend on many underlying factors such as presence of authoritarian versus democratic rule.’ And Torsten Persson at Stockholm University comments: ‘Hinges on economic and political structure (resource curse can operate via politics). Norway may not be hit, even though Nigeria may be.’

Finally, Robert Hall disagrees with the statement: ‘Countries with net exports of natural resources enjoy net benefits from favorable shifts in the terms of trade.’ And Kjetil Storesletten at the University of Oslo strongly disagrees: ‘Manufacturing firms can benefit from a resource boom if they can provide equipment servicing resource industry. Norway provides an example.’

All comments made by the experts are in the full survey results for Europe and the US.

Romesh Vaitilingam
@econromesh
July 2021

Question A:

The introduction of even small trade frictions between neighboring countries can result in significant economic damage, particularly to smaller exporting firms.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Question B:

A national economic boom based on natural resources is likely to harm other sectors of the economy, particularly manufacturing firms.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Question A Participant Responses

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Acemoglu
Daron Acemoglu
MIT
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
"Significant" here is very unclear. It can have a proportionately large effect on small firms, but unclear in the aggregate.
Altonji
Joseph Altonji
Yale
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Auerbach
Alan Auerbach
Berkeley
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Autor
David Autor
MIT
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
This is predicted by theory. But frictionless trade btw industrial countries is nonexistent. So, what does adding a "small" friction mean?
Baicker
Katherine Baicker
University of Chicago
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Banerjee
Abhijit Banerjee
MIT Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Bertrand
Marianne Bertrand
Chicago
Agree
2
Bio/Vote History
Brunnermeier
Markus Brunnermeier
Princeton
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Chetty
Raj Chetty
Harvard Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Chevalier
Judith Chevalier
Yale Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Cutler
David Cutler
Harvard
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Deaton
Angus Deaton
Princeton
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Duffie
Darrell Duffie
Stanford
Uncertain
2
Bio/Vote History
Edlin
Aaron Edlin
Berkeley Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Eichengreen
Barry Eichengreen
Berkeley
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Einav
Liran Einav
Stanford
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Fair
Ray Fair
Yale
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Not clear what "small" means.
Finkelstein
Amy Finkelstein
MIT
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Goldberg
Pinelopi Goldberg
Yale
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Goolsbee
Austan Goolsbee
Chicago
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Greenstone
Michael Greenstone
University of Chicago
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
Hall
Robert Hall
Stanford
Disagree
4
Bio/Vote History
Small frictions have small effects. And we should not be concerned with harm to firms or industries, only to people.
Hart
Oliver Hart
Harvard
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Under classical conditions small frictions have second order effects. So it depends on how important price rigidities, etc., are.
Holmström
Bengt Holmström
MIT
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Hoxby
Caroline Hoxby
Stanford
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
I tend to agree with the spirit of this query, but "small" trade frictions seem too poorly defined for me to give an answer. 1%, 5%, 10%?
Hoynes
Hilary Hoynes
Berkeley
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Judd
Kenneth Judd
Stanford
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Kaplan
Steven Kaplan
Chicago Booth
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Kashyap
Anil Kashyap
Chicago Booth
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Klenow
Pete Klenow
Stanford
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Levin
Jonathan Levin
Stanford
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
Maskin
Eric Maskin
Harvard
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Nordhaus
William Nordhaus
Yale
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Obstfeld
Maurice Obstfeld
Berkeley
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Saez
Emmanuel Saez
Berkeley
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Samuelson
Larry Samuelson
Yale
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
The presence of a home bias, in various forms, suggests that even small frictions can be important.
Scheinkman
José Scheinkman
Columbia University Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Schmalensee
Richard Schmalensee
MIT
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Shapiro
Carl Shapiro
Berkeley
Agree
2
Bio/Vote History
Shimer
Robert Shimer
University of Chicago
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Stock
James Stock
Harvard
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Thaler
Richard Thaler
Chicago Booth Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Udry
Christopher Udry
Northwestern
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
because, for example, network effects can generate feedback that reinforces the small frictions.

Question B Participant Responses

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Acemoglu
Daron Acemoglu
MIT
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
The answer would be yes for manufacturing that does not use the resource in question as input. Otherwise, it could be positive.
Altonji
Joseph Altonji
Yale
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Auerbach
Alan Auerbach
Berkeley
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Autor
David Autor
MIT
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Baicker
Katherine Baicker
University of Chicago
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Banerjee
Abhijit Banerjee
MIT Bio/Vote History
Bertrand
Marianne Bertrand
Chicago
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Brunnermeier
Markus Brunnermeier
Princeton
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Chetty
Raj Chetty
Harvard Bio/Vote History
Chevalier
Judith Chevalier
Yale Bio/Vote History
Cutler
David Cutler
Harvard
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Deaton
Angus Deaton
Princeton
Strongly Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Duffie
Darrell Duffie
Stanford
Disagree
2
Bio/Vote History
Edlin
Aaron Edlin
Berkeley Bio/Vote History
Eichengreen
Barry Eichengreen
Berkeley
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Effects depend on accompanying/offsetting policies.
Einav
Liran Einav
Stanford
Agree
1
Bio/Vote History
Fair
Ray Fair
Yale
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Finkelstein
Amy Finkelstein
MIT
Agree
2
Bio/Vote History
Goldberg
Pinelopi Goldberg
Yale Bio/Vote History
Not clear what "small" trade frictions are and what "significant" economic damage means.
Goolsbee
Austan Goolsbee
Chicago
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Greenstone
Michael Greenstone
University of Chicago
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Hall
Robert Hall
Stanford
Disagree
4
Bio/Vote History
Countries with net exports of natural resources enjoy net benefits from favorable shifts in the terms of trade
Hart
Oliver Hart
Harvard
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
My reading of the classic Corden-Neary paper is that the effects can be ambiguous.
Holmström
Bengt Holmström
MIT
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Hoxby
Caroline Hoxby
Stanford
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Hoynes
Hilary Hoynes
Berkeley
Uncertain
8
Bio/Vote History
Whether this were true or not would depend on many underlying factors such as presence of authoritarian vs democratic rule.
Judd
Kenneth Judd
Stanford
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Discovery of natural resources will reallocate factors of production, but no more so than other changes.
Kaplan
Steven Kaplan
Chicago Booth
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Kashyap
Anil Kashyap
Chicago Booth
Agree
1
Bio/Vote History
Klenow
Pete Klenow
Stanford
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Such booms crowd out employment in other sectors.
-see background information here
Levin
Jonathan Levin
Stanford
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
Maskin
Eric Maskin
Harvard
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Nordhaus
William Nordhaus
Yale
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Obstfeld
Maurice Obstfeld
Berkeley
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Saez
Emmanuel Saez
Berkeley
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Samuelson
Larry Samuelson
Yale
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Much depends on how the resource boom is handled; we have examples of cases that have worked well and examples of disasters.
Scheinkman
José Scheinkman
Columbia University Bio/Vote History
Schmalensee
Richard Schmalensee
MIT
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Shapiro
Carl Shapiro
Berkeley
Agree
2
Bio/Vote History
Shimer
Robert Shimer
University of Chicago
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
A natural resource boom drives up wages and other non-tradable prices, but this doesn't mean it is inefficient!
Stock
James Stock
Harvard
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Thaler
Richard Thaler
Chicago Booth Bio/Vote History
Udry
Christopher Udry
Northwestern
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History